In
the article “Fixing China’s Harmful Inequality”, Yukon Huang from the Wall
Street journal wrote about how China recently announced a plan to deal with
rising inequalities. He said that there was a problem reaching a consensus and
that the debate was unusually broad, ranging from the need for property taxes
and agricultural support prices to the role of the state in influencing returns
to firms and labor. It is not clear as to how this plan will effectively tackle
inequality because of the lack of detail and firm targets.
China’s
economy has rapidly grown, which has caused widening disparities. Their growth
has lifted about 600 million people out of poverty even as its Gini
coefficient, which is a measure of income inequality, has soared to 47% today
from 25% in the mid 1980’s. Despite the high statistics, China’s Gini is still
comparable to that of the U.S. and other successful Asian economies such as
Singapore and Malaysia. Huang gives an explanation about the significance of
the Gini number, “The Gini number is less important than the reasons behind it.
Inequality is positive when it emanates from productivity increases,
entrepreneurial risk-taking and structural changes that produce sustained
growth. Harmful inequality comes from distortions that ultimately undermine the
development process. It is the latter kind of inequality that Beijing has been
slow to address. First, policy distortions have exaggerated geographical
disparities. Second, the government budget has failed to provide equal access
to social services. And finally, links between government-party officials and
commercial activities have led to excessive rent-seeking.”
China’s
geographical inequality is actually extreme when compared to other countries.
Their per capita urban incomes are more than three times that of rural
residents, and coastal incomes are more than twice of the interior. Some of
blame can be because of the fast industrialization that has been going on along
the coast of China. You could also blame the policies such as restrictive
residency system known as hukou. Hukou prevents more than 200 million migrant
workers who have flocked to the major cities from gaining access to social
services and jobs on the same basis as established residents. This exacerbates
urban to rural and regional income disparities. The new plan has an intention
to liberalize the hukou system.
For
a socialist economy where the state controls the bulk of resources, the budget
plays a limited role in providing the level of social services needed to moderate
rising disparities. China’s budget as a share of the economy is only two-thirds
that of the other middle-income countries, and half that of the European Union,
and as a result welfare spending has been inadequate, amounting to about half
the level of comparable middle-income countries. Huang explains why budget
plays such a limited role, “The limited role of the budget reflects, in part, a
failure to secure more revenue from the state enterprises that control much of
the country's resources. Their profits have soared over the past decade given
their favored position, but compared with other countries, China's state
enterprises pay much less to the state in the form of dividends. Even these
modest amounts were largely allocated to other firms for investment rather than
made available to the budget for social services. Thus, the proposal to
increase payments by five percentage points is welcome, although this would
still be quite low compared to other countries.“
Another
source of harmful inequality is the linkage between the government-party
apparatus, state banks and enterprises. This leads to corrosive practices
ranging from clear cases of corruption to grey areas where conflicts of
interests and earnings built on relationships generate excessive incomes.
Senior leaders recognize that these issues threaten the legitimacy of the
political system. The new plan focuses on the symptoms of this problem by
demanding that officials report their income and assets. Huang explains that
there is much more needed to tackle the underlying causes and that at this
broadcast level, dealing with China’s bad inequalities will require a change in
the mindset regarding the importance of the rule of law, that is something
highly unlikely to happen quickly.
Reforms
to labor migration and divided policies could go a long way toward eliminating
bad inequalities. For example, channeling one-third of the overall profits of
state enterprises to the budget to fund social services for households would
help provide the resources necessary to equalize the quality of such programs
across regions. This combined with eliminating hukou restrictions might
increase household consumption by several percentage points of GDP. These
reforms would dramatically affect the nature of global macro imbalances by
increasing China’s imports. Dealing with the harmful sources of income inequality
not only addresses a social concern, it also offers a way to reduce trade
tensions between China and the West.
Article Link: http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424127887323549204578317633183827770.html
No comments:
Post a Comment